|
POLICY
The Great Balancing ActBy racing ahead of the WTO's deadlines for freeing imports with the new ExIm
Policy, Union Commerce Minister Ramakrishna Hegde has cleared the way for India Inc. to
plug into global trade. BT analyses the ExIm 99 trade strategy.
By Rukmini Parthasarthy
Export-Import (ExIm) Policies are,
usually, dull affairs. The Union Commerce Minister announces an ambitious export target,
tinkers with several export-promotion schemes, and cites Balance of Payments
considerations while randomly removing a few Quantitative Restrictions (QRS) on imports.
Union Commerce Minister Ramakrishna Hegde's first ExIm Policy, in 1998, stuck to this
formula. Fortunately, his second one does not.
For starters, there is no export target. Chastened by the
previous year's experience, when exports shrank by 1.60 per cent in the first 11 months
against a target of 15 per cent, the minister has refrained from projecting an export
growth rate. Over the same period, however, imports rose by 8.10 per cent, causing the
trade deficit to surge past $8 billion. But the deteriorating trade balance has not
stalled import liberalisation efforts. ExIm 99 has removed all restrictions on the import
of 894 items, and another 414 can now be imported against a Special Import Licence (SIL).
Observes B. Bhattacharyya, 55, Dean (Research), Indian Institute of Foreign Trade (IIFT),
Delhi: "The policy sensibly recognises that the government can no longer micro-manage
trade."
However, that does not mean that there is no macro-strategy
underlying ExIm 99. Undeterred by the uncertainty swirling the fate of his government,
Hegde used the occasion to unveil a surprisingly bold reforms agenda--to present his
vision of what needs to be done to get trade reforms moving once again.
THE EXIM 99 IMPORT STRATEGY. Accelerate the import
liberalisation process. The immediate pay-off: a stronger bargaining position at the World
Trade Organisation's (WTO) ministerial meet in November, 1999. In the long run, import
competition will help build industrial competitiveness.
"Long-term Trade Policy should work backwards from WTO norms to announce a
schedule so that industry can plan its adjustment"
R. Gopalakrishnan
Executive Director
Tata Sons
|
The logic is faultless, but the extent of acceleration
may be exaggerated. Through a series of bilateral agreements with Australia, Canada, New
Zealand, the European Union, Switzerland, and--more recently--Japan, the Government of
India had committed itself to a 3-stage phase-out of all QRS on imports by March 31, 2003
(a settlement has still not been reached with the US). As per these agreements, about
1,000 items had to be moved out of the restricted list in the first phase--i.e., by March
31, 2000. As ExIm 98 had lifted restrictions on only 340 items, ExIm 99 had to move at
least 660 items off the negative list. And pressure for an even-faster phase-out is likely
to intensify as the US wants all curbs to be removed immediately.
So, what items has Hegde liberalised ahead of schedule this
year? Mostly agricultural goods. Import restrictions on a host of vegetables (including
onions), fruits, dairy-products, and soya-products have been lifted. That does not pose
much threat to the domestic producers. India is, in any case, the world's third-largest
food producer and, in most cases, domestic prices are below world prices. Freer imports
will, however, benefit the domestic consumer. Since import decisions will no longer depend
on bureaucratic discretion, price-fluctuations will be ironed out quickly.
But if market forces are to operate freely, controls on
agricultural exports must also be dismantled. Although the lifting of all export controls
forms part of Hegde's reforms agenda, ExIm 99 does not prune the negative list of exports,
which consists largely of primary products. Points out Ashok Gulati, 45, NABARD Professor,
Institute of Economic Growth: "Blocking exports while freeing imports will minimise
the gains accruing to farmers from liberalisation."
As for corporates, gains in terms of improved competitiveness
will be maximised only if the QR phase-out is synchronised with other reforms. These
include Customs tariff cuts and the dereservation of products reserved exclusively for the
small-scale sector--measures that are beyond the purview of the Commerce Ministry. Sure,
by itself, the move to switch from quotas to tariff-based protection will limit the degree
of inefficiency. Competition from imports should force corporates to move into the high
quality-low cost spectrum, which, in turn, will help them compete in export markets.
"The government should transform the exports incentive regime from one that
subsidises inefficiency to one that promotes efficiency."
T.K. Bhaumik
Senior Policy Advisor, CII
|
But the impetus for such improvements will be feeble if
tariff-walls are high. The bulk of industrial items that have been delicensed will attract
the peak Customs duty rate of 40 per cent--far higher than tariff rates in other
countries. Indeed, the next round of negotiations under the WTO is likely to push for much
lower industrial tariff bindings. Argues R. Gopalakrishnan, 53, Executive Director, Tata
Sons: "Convergence towards WTO norms is the end-point. Long-term trade policy should
work backwards from there to announce a tariff-adjustment schedule so that industry can
plan its adjustment."
Dereservation too should proceed according to a schedule
since current policies have created a mess. While successive budgets have dereserved
select items haphazardly, successive ExIm policies have progressively placed products
reserved for the small-scale sector on the Open General Licence list. Of the 830 odd items
reserved for the small-scale sector, about 660 now operate under a free-trade regime. In
effect, small Indian firms are competing with large-scale imports. And reservation
prevents them from investing in the scale and technology necessary to take on those
imports. "There is a policy contradiction but, then, dereservation requires political
consensus," admits N.L. Lakhanpal, 56, Director-General of Foreign Trade.
Unfortunately, by the time that elusive consensus is reached, QRS may be long gone.
THE EXIM 99 EXPORT STRATEGY. Streamline export
incentive schemes to reduce transactions cost. To cut through a tangle of procedures,
develop Free Trade Zones (FTZs), and involve the states in export promotion.
Reducing the procedural clutter infesting various export
incentive schemes does not amount to an export strategy. It will only trim transaction
costs. And not by much. Complains Navratan Samadria, 48, President, Federation of Indian
Exporters: "The Commerce Ministry cannot really do anything. It is the harassment by
Customs officials and limitations imposed by an inadequate infrastructure that are
responsible."
Indeed, the only way to effectively rationalise incentive
schemes is to simply phase them out. Argues T.K. Bhaumik, 48, Senior Policy Advisor,
Confederation of Indian Industry (CII): "Administration of these schemes spawns a web
of procedures; the schemes themselves are non-transparent, and malpractice, rampant."
Worse, they are also counter-productive. Globally, as tariff-barriers fall, new non-tariff
barriers rise. Especially worrying for Indian exporters has been the increasing use of
anti-subsidy or countervailing measures by our trading partners.
Under the WTO's rules, subsidies are boxed into 3 categories:
prohibited subsidies, actionable subsidies, and non-actionable subsidies. Prohibited, or
red-box subsidies include all forms of export subsidies, which developing countries must
phase out by 2003 if they have a per capita income exceeding $1,000 (Rs 42,000). Although
India is far from reaching that level, Commerce Ministry officials have indicated that
export subsidies that have been notified to the WTO will be withdrawn.
Explicit export subsidies include the income-tax exemption
for export income, concessional interest rates on export finance, and SIL premiums.
Licences, which allow the exporter to import items that are otherwise restricted, can be
sold for a premium to importers, and, therefore, amount to an outright cash subsidy.
However, as more items are moved to the free list, premiums will automatically drop.
Already, they have crashed to less than 1 per cent. Yet, ExIm 99 has chosen to reverse the
process by arbitrarily tripling the value SILs will fetch upon their surrender. Hiking
subsidies that are supposed to be phased out will only create uncertainty for the
exporter.
Also unclear is which box schemes like the Duty Entitlement
Passbook Scheme fall into. Drawback schemes typically seek to reimburse the exporter for
all the taxes paid on production. Rebates on indirect taxes for exports is an
internationally-accepted practice; excessive rebates are not. Given our opaque indirect
tax structure, determining whether rebates are excessive or not is a matter of judgement.
Exporters claim that the incidence of local taxes is not neutralised, and that refunds are
subject to massive delays. Our trading partners, however, contend that excessive rebates
have resulted in price-undercutting and are, therefore, actionable subsidies. Until we
move to a comprehensive value-added tax system, the disputes will continue.
In the interim, switching to non-actionable or green-box
subsidies would be a smart strategy. Assistance for R&D, concessions for brand
promotion, and facilitation of technology imports are allowed under international trading
rules. So, do away with income-tax exemptions, but provide rebates for expenditure on
r&d. Abolish complicated drawback schemes, but allow for the free import of
technology. Phase out interest rate subsidies on export finance, but provide
venture-capital support to brand-development programmes. Sums up CII's Bhaumik:
"Transform the incentive regime from one that subsidises inefficiency to one that
promotes efficiency."
The advantages go far beyond circumvention of the growing
number of anti-subsidy actions. A green-box export regime will provide a thrust to
fast-growing service exports; it will also help propel existing exports up the value
ladder. Agrees Vasant Kumar, 38, Director, Strategic Planning, Ranbaxy Laboratories:
"In the US, policy support to R&D helped hone competitive advantage in
knowledge-based exports; here, a policy structure based on sops ensured that our exports
remained at the bottom of the food-chain."
Indeed. Resource-based and low-tech exports account for 80
per cent of our total exports. The global average is 35 per cent. Worse, nearly two-thirds
of our manufacturing exports consist of products whose share in world trade is declining.
So, although volumes have been growing, unit value realisations have been falling--a grim
indicator of both the extent of price-competition that the majority of Indian exports
face, and the low rung of the value chain they occupy. Says Arindam Banik, 40, Professor
(International Economics), International Management Institute: "There is no way we
can have export-led growth unless our export basket, which has remained the same over the
last 50 years, changes."
The basket has not changed because, for much of the last 50
years, ExIm Policies have looked at the trade sector in isolation from the rest of the
economy. But barriers between the domestic market and the global market are crumbling,
eroding the ability of ExIm Policies to manipulate export profitability and influence
trading patterns. To its credit, ExIm 99 recognises its own diminished role. Asks
Lakhanpal: "In a liberalised economy, why do we need an ExIm Policy?"
Yet, we do need a trade policy that is integrated with an
overall investment policy. Many of the measures outlined by Hegde--dereservation, changes
in labour laws, tax reforms--are beyond the purview of his ministry. But they have to form
part of the trade reforms agenda of any government. The present ExIm Policy has recognised
its limitations. Hopefully, a future trade policy will begin to tackle these limitations.
'Personally, I
Would Like To Disappear'
He hope that ExIm 99 will make him redundant. N.L. Lakhanpal, 56,
the Director-General of Foreign Trade, explains why to BT's Rukmini Parthasarthy. Excerpts
from an exclusive interview:
The highlight of ExIm 99 has been the acceleration of
the import liberalisation process. What was the rationale for the acceleration?
With this policy, we have met all our
Phase-I obligations for the removal of Quantitative Restrictions on imports. We chose to
accelerate the liberalisation of items where duty protection is already high. So, even
though the manufacturer has some protection, he is exposed to competition. You can no
longer be inefficient and survive. We are now on the threshold of a New Millennium. It is
time we discarded the baggage of being a developing country which is entitled to
concessions. We should deal with other countries as an equal trading partner.
Why wasn't the negative list for exports also pruned?
Export restrictions are mostly on food items. To phase these
out, we will have to intensively examine our food requirements. Food security is
paramount. Of course, all controls should go--and will go. The question is of pace. That
will be determined in consultation with the Ministry of Agriculture.
The coordination between ministries seems to be
rather poor. The Labour Ministry is objecting to the proposal to amend labour laws for
Free Trade Zones (FTZs)
To the contrary, the co-ordination between ministries has
been excellent. Sure, everyone argues intensely but when, finally, a statement of policy
emerges, it is based on consensus. Besides, the Commerce Minister did not say that labour
laws would not apply to the ftzs. He simply said that the issue would be examined.
Will FTZs be viable if labour laws are not amended?
In China, FTZs allow flexibility to hire--and fire.
It is a mistake to keep citing the Chinese example. China is
a Socialist economy; it had to create those zones to attract foreign investment. India has
always been a relatively freer economy. A more valid comparison is provided by the
American ftzs. All the laws of the land, including labour laws, apply to their ftzs. Of
course, there can be a case for reforming the law for the entire country, not just for the
ftzs.
Isn't the fall in unit-value realisation of exports
reflective of the structural problems with our exports?
This is a temporary decline. Our exports are facing stiff
competition from East Asian economies as their currencies have depreciated considerably.
Our exporters have had to slash prices to stay in the market.
But we are vulnerable to such depreciations because
we have failed to build value into our products
Yes, unfortunately, that has been the trend. We did not
design our economy for exports; the emphasis was on self-sufficiency. Since there was a
complete clamp-down on imports, there was no need for industry to export because the
domestic market was fully protected. The imperatives of quality and of brand-building were
never faced. With increased competition from imports, those imperatives will now have to
be faced.
Isn't it also imperative to phase out all export
subsidies? Many of our trading partners are slapping anti-subsidy duties on our exports
The problem arises because our taxation system is complicated
and its anti-subsidy investigations are motivated. Refund of the indirect taxes which
exporters are required to pay at various stages is a worldwide convention. The only
difference is that most countries have a straightforward system of final tax whereas we do
not have a full value-added tax. Since we also have multiple taxing authorities, there are
multiple schemes to provide refunds. These are conveniently dubbed as subsidies by our
trading partners. Once we have rationalised and simplified our taxation structure, they
will lose that handle.
What about the premium on Special Import Licences
(SILs)? That is an outright cash subsidy
Our trading partners have recognised sil as an intermediate
stage between the free list and the restricted list. Yes, to that extent, it is a subsidy.
Section 80 HHC (of the Income Tax Act, 1961) is also a subsidy that has been notified to
the World Trade Organisation. We are not hiding this; these will be phased out.
As these are phased out, the role of ExIm Policy will
shrink
It should shrink. Why should we influence trade patterns? As
long as we can remove obstacles, it is enough. Other countries do not have ExIm policies.
Ideally, we need to move to a situation where business is left to the businessman, and
exports are left to the exporter.
What, then, will the Directorate-General of Foreign
Trade do?
Personally, I would like to disappear. |
|