Nuclear
weapons engineering and weather prediction have to use supercomputer
simulations. This is because they are systems that are not predictable,
in any practical sense, by studying the equations of physics. They
exhibit 'complex emergent systems' behaviour with (some notion of)
order arising out of chaos, just as wind tunnel simulations often
show unforeseen behaviour that would have been impractical to discover
theoretically.
Similarly, the central thesis of Paving Wall
Street: Experimental Economics & the Quest for the Perfect Market
by Ross M. Miller, is that economic simulations can test practical
issues related to market mechanisms in ways that theoretical economics
cannot.
This engagingly written story of the little-known
area of Experimental Economics is inspired by the author's work
with Vernon L. Smith, who shared the 2002 Nobel prize in Economics.
The book first answers one of the most vexing fundamental questions
of economics: how does the 'Invisible Hand' work whereby mass opinions
somehow come together and manage the economy better than could,
say, a well-educated intellectual planner?
|
Paving Wall Street
By Ross M. Miller
John Wiley & Sons
Price: Rs 1,500
PP: 174
|
The book shows how Vernon
Smith's clever economic experiments demonstrated the robustness
of F.A. Hayek's famous hypothesis that markets can allocate stuff
efficiently even without perfect information available to all participants,
if bids and offers are the only information traders reveal.
Economic experiments are simply simulations
of a market, using experimental subjects as traders and highly simplified
rules to capture the economic essence of a trading situation. To
everyone's astonishment, such simplistic classroom games showed
results remarkably similar to real markets. First, prices rapidly
converged to the efficient equilibrium point, as if everyone had
perfect information.
Furthermore, even more interestingly, Smith's
experimental markets showed many complex and mysterious effects
such as bubbles and crashes, for which neo-classical economics still
has no good explanation but often occur in real markets.
Miller also describes how Experimental Economics
has shown that forward markets can prevent or reduce the formation
of bubbles. For this part alone, this book is a 'must-read' for
anyone considering the issue of forward trading in Indian stockmarkets.
The only pity is that Miller spends far too little time explaining
his ideas on why derivatives prevent bubbles and crashes, compared
to the extensive and clear expositions he presents about everything
else.
On a bigger picture level, this book is significant
in the 'uber-paradigm' it represents: the interdisciplinary nexus
of Artificial Intelligence (AI) and Economics, which is a trend
necessitated by data overload. Tech fads and bubbles may come and
go, but we will always have to deal with worsening data overload.
And this will intertwine machine learning, data mining and automated
decision-systems increasingly in every facet of life. The fact that
Google has now become a verb as well as a noun is the most obvious
example.
Sure enough, Miller's pet idea is the 'Smart
Market', an intelligent market mechanism that allows for more efficient
information aggregation and price discovery, and leads to better
trade executions for all market participants in general.
The reader may then be motivated to explore
further the economics-machine learning nexus, and look at how this
new paradigm leads to results almost unattainable so far. For example,
the new learning systems technology of Kernel Machines can now develop,
in a day, a system for postal services to read handwritten addresses
automatically, which matches the accuracy that took years of engineering
work using the older Neural Network technology. Besides Wall Street,
areas as diverse as marketing, medical research and even real estate
are now beginning to feel the effects of the orders-of-magnitude
level breakthrough represented by this new paradigm. But then, that's
a subject for elaboration in another column.
|
The Burden Of Democracy
By Pratap Bhanu Mehta
Penguin
Price: Rs 195
PP: 176
|
Would
you judge Indian democracy at face value? Try it. Not democracy
as an artificial ideal that's worshipped, but as a human-formulated
satisfier of human needs-a very wide set, in this case, including
the presumed need to keep any romantic eyes from welling up in tears.
India's economic imperative, of course, is rapid GDP growth-and
Jawaharlal Nehru University professor Pratap Bhanu Mehta acknowledges
the failure of redistributive policies; but this growth still needs
to be the kind that's long-term sustainable rather than fissiparous.
What makes India's post-1947 democracy experiment
peculiar, Mehta contends, is that it was not preceded by a cohesively
passionate revolution against social inequality (even the 'transfer-of-power'
was fissured). Indian democracy since has internalised old inequities-as
evident in today's identity politics. Thus India's ''burden of democracy'',
paradoxically, is its continuing inequality-which, as he quotes
a Japanese businessman as observing, subverts the merit-based allocation
of human resources so crucial to global success. Had Mehta asked
a Chinese, he might also have identified that other big agony, the
demographic disadvantage of Indian inequality: disproportionately
small domestic markets. Simply put, too many marginalised at home
make for too little business power globally.
To help market reforms empower India Inc, Mehta
recommends granting the marginalised a stake in the process. Sure
enough, Tocqueville's concerns on tyranny find due place in this
zippy 176-page read, as also a plea for equity on the negation of
''natural authority''.
What's critically needed is the liberty to
debate it all, as Harvard man Fareed Zakaria might say, arguing
that democracy was preceded by liberty in the West, and it's constitutional
liberalism that deserves precedence even now. And if thrive a country
must, rule must the Law.
Yet, it's a struggle satisfying all the needs
democracy ought to. The 1990s' opening up of the one arena in India
that influences democracy most-news media-to audience buyers, but
not really sellers, has given us an AI-happy 'market' that favours
audience size vastly over diversity, thus cramping the choice space
for both information and ideas. Sad.
-Aresh Shirali
|