Judging
by the strange silence on the subject, no one, not even superannuated
souls over 60 managing the op-ed pages of news-dailies seems to
give a damn that the real interest rate, as this sentence is being
written, has turned negative. That's right, negative, as in minus,
below zero. Today, the return on deposits (with a maturity of more
than a year) at commercial banks is between 5.25 per cent and 6
per cent. The yield on 10-year G-secs (government securities) is
around 5.8 per cent. With inflation (based on the Wholesale Price
Index) hovering just below the 6 per cent mark, it doesn't take
a John Nash to figure out that the real interest rate is negative.
Attribute the phenomenon to India's desire
to be in step with the rest of the world, an economic sentiment
respected by the country's central bank, Reserve Bank of India.
In the six years between 1997 and 2003, RBI has slashed the benchmark
bank rate by 600 basis points or 6 per cent-for the record, at 6
per cent, this rate is close to where it was 30 years ago. The central
bank has also reduced the Cash Reserve Ratio (CRR) and Statutory
Liquidity Ratio (SLR), thereby increasing the availability of money
in the system. If numbers aren't your scene, all these fancy ratios
and numbers simply translate into a soft interest rate regime. That's
likely to continue: the best Indian companies can raise debt abroad
at 4 per cent (including foreign exchange cover); the cheapest they
can raise money in India is 5.5 per cent. Ergo, expect the bank
rate to travel further south.
Classical economic thinking has it that a low
interest rate will improve an economy's productivity. Companies,
the logic goes, will restructure their debt, and take on more as
part of an effort to grow. And retail consumers will use debt to
finance everything from televisions to cars to homes. The same school
of thought also posits that should real interest rates fall below
zero, people will have no incentive to save. Doing the requisite
two-plus-two addition, the present interest rate regime should boost
consumer spending and stifle household savings and capital formation.
And by doing the latter, it should nip the emerging economic recovery
in the bud.
Unfortunately, the Indian economy doesn't seem
to recognise classical economics. Yes, it's possible for the real
interest rate to remain negative in the short term without impacting
capital formation. There is recent historical evidence that supports
this: in the second half of 1998, inflation, albeit, that based
on Consumer Price Index, zoomed to 20 per cent, and was higher than
the then prevailing interest rate-this phenomenon was temporary.
Still, the Indian response to a negative interest
rate is original. Despite the desire for higher returns, Indians
will continue to invest in the only safe option before them, bank
deposits; their faith in the equities market has been shaken by
a spate of scams. Indeed, bank deposits continue to grow, although
the rate of growth is lower than it was in the past. More worryingly,
a low interest rate may force people into saving more so as to earn
as much as they would have if the interest rate had been higher.
That would reduce consumer spending.
It'll be unfortunate if that happens because
companies are loath to invest in additional capacities, despite
funds being available at attractive rates, in the absence of a surge
in consumer demand. Already, banks are witnessing a sluggish credit
growth and most of their incremental deposits are being invested
in government securities, driving the interest rate further south.
The end result, however, will remain the same as the one forecast
by classical economics: no economic recovery.
Which is why, as we in this magazine have repeatedly
chorused, macro-economic factors will have less to do with a recovery,
when it happens, than good old consumer sentiment and private enterprise's
ability to convince consumers that they need a particular product
or service. Circa, June 2003, it looks like Marketing 101 has put
one over Economics 101.
|